Part
VII of ‘England in Arms’
By
W. Lacey Amy
From
The Canadian Magazine, November 1917
To date the problem faced in the feeding of the
people of the British Isles is not that of food shortage, but of food
distribution. To the foreigner that assertion may seem to deprive the situation
of most of its seriousness; to us who live through it and watch its development
therein lies more menace than in the expressed hopes of the Kaiser. British
ingenuity may be depended upon more confidently to overcome the enemy than to
alter internal affairs in order to cope with unusual conditions. Nothing is so
powerful against the Englishman as his habits and system.
No one in the British Isles has felt the pinch
of hunger. And it is not likely that anyone will. What suffering there has
been arises from the temporary shortage of unessentials and from high prices.
Sugar and potatoes sum up the total of national deprivations owing to the war,
and never did they approach privations because there has always been something
to take their places. Before there is actual want the British will have solved
the submarine. But after three years of a situation that has continually
pointed to food as one of the vital factors in the winning of victory they are
only now nearing the solution of a situation with which the enemy has nothing
to do—which is, indeed, indigenous to the British race, but more particularly
to that section of it residing in England and Scotland.
The problem of distribution is twofold. The
limitation of supplies—rather the necessity of conserving for an
uncertain future—demands an equality of distribution that ignored
individuals and class. The second difficulty is the British
character—an independence which resents control and
dictation. Of the two the latter was the more immediately dangerous at the
beginning of the conservation movement. But common sense is
asserting itself, so that equality of distribution now occupies the time of
the Food Controller. When he
found temperance in
eating to be so necessary as
to justify Government action,
the Englishman yielded
to a pressure which he
naturally resists. But having
yielded, he was forced to set to work on
the national system of class
favouritism—as, indeed, he has
been forced to do in every
problem connected with
the war.
It was Britain’s unquestioned command of
the seas that delayed food measures which were reasonable from the
very first gun. That inbred and time-honoured confidence in victory laid a
heavy hand on reasonable provision and prevision in every act of war. In the
matter of food arbitrary measures did not seem to be necessary early in the
struggle. Depending entirely, as it did, on the control of the seas, Great
Britain was justified in her confidence, a confidence that would never have
been shaken had the Germans adhered to the rules of warfare.
One measure only was taken early in the war to
protect the food supply of the British Isles, an obvious one immediately
demanded by the fact that they had been procuring more than sixty per cent. of
their sugar from Germany. A Sugar Commission was appointed. Thereafter, for
more than two years, even when the casual onlooker was viewing the situation
with alarm and the Asquith Government itself was talking much of plans in the
House, nothing further was done. Always in the mind of the people was the
thought that the enemy could not drive Great Britain to defensive measures that
would reflect upon its special sphere of power; and in the mind of the
Government was the hope that political balances need not be disturbed by
restrictive action certain to be resented in some quarters. For it must not be
imagined that party aims and hopes disappeared with the formation of a
Coalition Cabinet.
The second official move of importance was made
in October, 1916, when a Wheat Commission undertook to readjust the grain
situation. Unfortunately it was weighted down with the Asquith love of laisser-faire, and its duties never materialized into effective
action. At a time when the enemy was openly sinking merchant vessels and
threatening more, when the demands of military operations and national supply
were so deflecting shipping from the ordinary channels of food transportation
that reserves of grain in the British Isles were being seriously depleted, no
action was taken towards replenishing these supplies from a world’s production
that was above the normal. America and Australia were offering the grain, but
England was not willing
to disturb the trend of affairs in order to facilitate the acceptance of the
offers.
The press of England was becoming alive to the
menace, and the English press has a voice more powerful than that of its
brother across the ocean. The people were growing anxious. The difficulty of
securing sugar was impressing even the thoughtless with the need for action.
Mr. Asquith was forced to promise operations which were loathsome to him, not
alone for their antagonism to his policy, but for the danger he well saw would
arise therefrom to his personal popularity. He announced the establishment of
a new department headed by a Food Controller. It promised well. But the Food
Controller was never appointed. Week after week the country waited. Mr.
Asquith was at his best in his promises of what that important official would
do—in his explanations of the delay. He was at his most natural in his
inability to come to the point of action.
It was the accumulation of such dilatory acts as
these that brought about his downfall. Just three days before an anxious
Cabinet, backed by a roused people, demanded his resignation, Mr. Runciman,
one of his Ministers, placed before the country one lone food measure that even
then looked like a small mouse for the mountain to bring forth. Restrictions
were placed on restaurant fare—or rather attempted restrictions. Luncheon was
to be a two-course meal and the ample English restaurant dinner was to be
limited to three courses.
With that heritage Lloyd George assumed power.
His first discovery in connection with the food situation was that his predecessor
had taken no inventory of the nation’s supplies, had made no move to simplify
the work of the Food Department, which had immediately to be organized. One of
the first officials appointed in the new Government was a Food Controller, Lord Devonport, a man whose intimate
connection with food supply as the head of a large multiple store company
seemed to qualify him for the position. It was a disappointment to the country
and to the Premier himself that the seeming qualifications for the
Controller’s office should in the end prove the insuperable obstacle to his
effectiveness. Lord Devonport introduced many measures intended to cope with a
situation passing rapidly into a serious stage, but a calm survey of them
discovers them to be, after all, paltry, a
mere touching of the surface.
Lord Devonport took pleasure in vetoing the
Runciman restaurant order four months after it had been put into effect, and
almost the same time after its folly had become evident. The limited course
meal brought only one result, that diners ate more solid meat, and less of the
odds and ends, the entrees and unessentials and make-overs, that give the
daintiest touch to restaurant fare without affecting food stocks. Men formerly
content with a small helping of meat in the interests of the
decorative courses, demanded meat and bread and cheese, the basis
of subsistence.
The new Food Controller, too, was forced to deal with bread, tea, confectionery,
potatoes and other vegetables, and sugar.
His substitute for the
Runciman restaurant control was a meatless day and a limitation of the amounts
of meat, bread and sugar served at each meal. This was later altered because of
its drain on bread in order to take the place of meat on the meatless day.
Bread he attempted to regulate by prohibiting its sale until twelve hours after
baking, and by limiting its shape, weight and constituents. The adulteration of flour by
maize or rice, and the prohibition of the waste that
produces white flour, resulted in what is known
as war bread. It was an effective measure,
despite the continued opposition of the people. Tea—considered
in England almost as great
a food necessity as bread—was regulated in its cheaper qualities. A curb was
put on the use of sugar in confectionery, pastry and icing. In the early part
of 1917 potatoes were passing so rapidly into the list of shortages that price
limitation was necessary. Three cents a pound for old stock was established for
the early months, rising later a half-cent. But no measures could increase the
supply, and no attempt was made to prevent the farmers holding their stocks
for higher prices. For months it might be said there were no potatoes in
England. And with the failure of potatoes the vegetable substitutes advanced
until the Food Controller was forced to limit the price of some of them.
Where Lord Devonport failed was in his
reluctance to take a firm stand, to
enforce the law, and principally to curtail
the profits of the trader. He
attempted to solve the problem by appeal.
A chart of patriotic proportions in the daily diet was flung at the public in a
thousand ways. The fences were covered with it, the newspapers gave
it daily
space, lecturers flooded the
country, and, at a time when the
shortage of paper was serious, the workingmen’s pay envelopes were crammed
with a literature he never read. To
the credit of the country the
consumption of bread and meat materially decreased. But the two insuperable
obstacles to success were the inability of ninety per cent. of the people to
purchase the advised ration of sugar and the eagerness of some to seize the
opportunity for gorging. While there were millions willing to curb their
appetites there were flaunting thousands of pro-German sympathies or utter
carelessness whose delight it was to evade the appeal and
the laws. And at the very time when the people were begged to stint themselves
interned and imprisoned Germans
were allowed many times the ration; sugar and
potatoes were being commandeered for them
when the workers of the country had to
go without. The inconsistencies of the situation were intolerable, and the
effectiveness of the appeal diminished weekly.
In the matter of enforcing the law there was
singular laxness. Here and there a dealer was fined, although it was impossible
to go on the streets without seeing plainly advertised infractions of the food
laws. And the fine was usually but a small part of the profit made from the
illicit transaction. Indeed, there was apparent, in store and home and
restaurant, a merry revelry of law evasion that undid the patriotism of those
who honestly rationed themselves.
Profiteering went on without restriction. Lord
Devonport, head of a big grocery concern, persisted in refusing to limit the
profits of grocers save in a few glaring and insignificant cases. Swedes, for
instance, the substitute for potatoes, were limited in price to three cents a
pound, a price so many times what the farmer and greengrocer had been receiving
that neither could complain. The setting of prices for potatoes and beans was
much advertised but unimportant, for both disappeared from the market almost
immediately. Although the cost of bread to miller and baker was materially
decreased by the new laws, the price advanced instantly to the consumer two to
four cents a four-pound loaf. While a few bakers outside London were content
with the profits from seventeen-cent bread, the London baker charged
twenty-four. The attempt to democratize tea was a failure. Forty per cent. of
the importations were to be sold to the public at fifty-two and fifty-six
cents, but no one was ever able to purchase a pound of the cheaper price, to my
knowledge, and if the better quality of Government tea was inquired for it was
either out of stock or sneered at by the grocer. Neither price was ever displayed
in the windows during Lord Devonport’s term. The same happened with cheese. A
large part of it was taken over by the Government to be sold over the counter
for thirty-two cents, but it never appeared on the shelves of more than a very
few stores.
With meat no attempt was made to interfere until
the last days of Lord Devonport’s office, and then only the speculator was
eliminated, the retailer being permitted to ask what he pleased. Of the
retailers the butcher was the most heartless profiteer, the consumer being
asked sixty to one hundred and fifty per cent. profit over the wholesale
prices. Even the supplies controlled by the Government, such as New Zealand
mutton, were turned loose upon arrival in England for the wholesaler and
retailer to make what profit he wished. Laid down in London by the Government
at thirteen cents, it reached the public at thirty-six to sixty cents. The
butcher could not buy it without a large purchase of English mutton at
extravagant prices. And in the meantime, in order to maintain the level of
prices, tons of meat were left to rot on the docks.
There is no better example of the injudicious
and unfair distribution of supplies than sugar, the commodity that has induced
several crises already. To the people the only result of the Sugar Commission
was an immediate rise in price. Against this there has been constant
complaint, for it is known that the rise represented taxation and Government
profit. It was not until the latter part of 1916 that a shortage began seriously
to be felt; but from the first pinch the shortage increased until stocks seemed
to have disappeared from the market, so far as the poorer classes were
concerned. By December women were walking the streets from shop to shop begging
half-pounds. Queues had not then commenced, because sugar was the only shortage
and the grocer sold only to whom he liked.
It is this independence of the merchant that
has driven home to the country the disaster of typical official control, so
called. Each week the Sugar Commission
released to the wholesalers their shares of the available supplies, and washed
their hands of any further connection with the commodity. Theoretically the
wholesaler was supposed to pass on to the grocer his share, but that he had
favourites is proved by the fact that some of the large West End stores seemed
never to be without sugar, while the small grocer of the East End was denied a
pound. It must be remembered that every pound of sugar shipped to England was
Government-controlled. No control whatever was exercised over the retailer
save in the matter of price, and the shortage of the available supplies enabled
him to make sugar the basis of his trade. He sold to whom he pleased in the
quantities he pleased. His independence became impudence. A customer was always
a beggar, for he was entirely at the mercy of his grocer. Sugar was denied
those who could not afford to make their purchases extravagant. Some system
seemed to arrive with the demand for a purchase of fifty cents’ worth of other
goods with each half-pound or pound of sugar, and this was accepted by the
authorities as a wise provision against wasteful purchases of the limited
commodity. It was the strength of class in England that for many months
prevented the authorities from realizing that such a stipulation reserved
sugar for the rich who could afford to buy supplies they did not need in order
to obtain the sugar they did. It was only when the merchants began to extend
the same demand to the purchase of other foodstuffs that the Government
forbade any conditions with the sale of sugar. But the grocer was still left to
sell to whom he pleased. No improvement whatever resulted, since the grocer
simply refused to sell until another large order was given.
The cry of the poor—the long, hopeless queues,
the untrained cooks helpless to provide for their large families without that
which had made up such a large part of their food—was
pitiful. And all the time the West End shops were selling it in fifty-pound
lots or less. The Government’s loose effort to enable fruit-growers to preserve
their fruit was equally unfair. The growers sent in their requirements, and
the sugar was released to the grocer mentioned in the requisition, but without
any control over the amount he passed on to the grower. Of four friends, no two
received the same proportion of that which they had asked for, the amount
varying from fifty to ninety per cent. No one knows what the grocer should have
given out. The latest measure in the handling of sugar, to come into force in
October, is a form of card supply, but still there is no safeguard that the
grocer will sell to his customers their individual shares of the available
supplies.
The clamorous protest arising was more than
threatening. Lord Devonport accepted the inevitable and resigned. Lord Rhondda
assumed the thankless job. It is typical of English public life that only a
titled man is considered competent to undertake public work. The war has
introduced a Geddes or two; others will have to follow. Particularly
unfortunate in the matter of controlling resources is this habit, since these
wealthy titled men are so closely concerned in a financial way with the
industries and commerce of the country that unprejudiced outlook is nigh to
impossible. Lord Rhondda had made good in his first Government office and in
private life, and initiative was not lacking. His misfortune was that he was appointed
at a time when public impatience would not brook delay. Without time to study
the situation and devise methods he was driven to instant action. The result
was a hundred more or less vague promises that seemed to fit in with the
demands of the people, and one act only of the immediate future. Profiteering
was the bête noire of the people, and on profiteering he came out
strong—in word.
Thus far there is only the promise that profiteering will be punished by
imprisonment. Speculation is to be stopped, how is not apparent. Lord Devonport
had already issued orders to that effect in the case of meat without affecting
much the price to the consumer. The only definite act which would tend to
soothe the people was an obvious expedient. It dealt with the commodity most familiar
to the table—bread. Bread was ordered to be sold—some time in the future—at
eighteen cents a quartern loaf.
Realizing that the British Isles might be called
upon to depend upon their own resources, he turned to the farmer. Land was
tilled that had never been broken for centuries, and the farmer became a real
producer. If he didn’t, there was a law to take his land from him temporarily.
Ploughing was done by tractor, night and day and Sundays. The added crop
acreage was expected to amount to millions, but lack of tractors and help and
quick co-operation reduced the amount to less than half a million acres. Next
year the millions are promised. Allotments sprang up everywhere—vacant lots,
golf links, railway tracks, parks. London alone is producing eight hundred
extra acres of vegetables. The additional growth has reduced the price of potatoes
for the moment to less than it was before the war; and the absence of market
organization is leaving tons to rot, England was driven to act before she could
complete the organization necessary to reap the greatest reward.
The solution does not yet appear. If the
submarine continues even its present success, and the measures of the future do
not improve substantially on those of the past, the British Isles will feel
want. Private profits, private shipping, block all the Government can do. The
controlling influences of supply and demand are non-existent in time of war.
With Government interference they lost almost all their power, in all justice.
To continue that power is to exploit the Government of the people at the cost
of the people. To-day the old tenet of the economist means nothing more, in the
case of importations, than to ask the people, at their own expense, to make
trade possible by import regulations and transportation protection, and then
to expect them to pay the trader according to the volume and expense of that
protection. And locally-grown products are directly dependent for price,
especially in England, on the available stocks from without.
The stopping of profiteering is a pleasant
ambition to talk about but an over-lofty one to anticipate. Profiteering does
not end with the grocer and butcher, the wholesaler and shipper. It has
entered into every phase of home life. Only the man in khaki, who assumes all
the risk of war, is precluded from it. The workingman, the clerk, the farmer,
the thousands of Government officials who have risen with the war—even the
Government itself—are profiting from the war. But the burden is uneven. The
workingman of England can present a good defence in terms of comparative wage
scale, but in terms of total receipt—which is the basis of his living—he might
be called a profiteer. His five pence an hour of pre-war days may have
increased only sixty per cent., while living has advanced one hundred; but his
week’s envelope contains probably three times—often six and ten times—what it
did before the war. The decreased facilities for drink and idleness keep him
longer at work, and the additions of bonus and overtime are not infrequently
greater than his regular wage.
The next article of this series
will discuss the elaborate plans being made in England
for the conservation of materials.
No comments:
Post a Comment